Εάν
η υποτίμηση του ελληνικού χρέους είχε γίνει σε δραχμές, θα είχε
αποτραπεί η ύφεση, υποστηρίζεται σε δημοσίευμα της εφημερίδας New York
Times, στο οποίο γίνεται αναφορά στα «συγκριτικά πλεονεκτήματα» που
κατέχουν οι ΗΠΑ από πλευράς δανειοληψίας, σε σχέση με άλλες χώρες που
δανείζονται σε ξένο νόμισμα.
Όπως τονίζεται, οι ΗΠΑ
μπορούν και δανείζονται σε δικό τους νόμισμα, με εξαιρετικά χαμηλά
επιτόκια αλλά και υπό την αμερικανική νομοθεσία, γεγονός που καθιστά
αδύνατη την προοπτική μιας αναγκαστικής χρεοκοπίας.
Αντιθέτως,
πολλά κράτη δεν έχουν αυτή την πολυτέλεια, καθώς όταν δανείζονται σε
διεθνές επίπεδο, ο δανεισμός πραγματοποιείται σε ξένο νόμισμα και τα
ομόλογα διευκρινίζουν συχνά ότι οποιοδήποτε μελλοντική διαφωνία θα
διευθετηθεί υπό ξένη νομοθεσία, συνήθως υπό τον αμερικανικό ή το
βρετανικό νόμο, σημειώνεται.
Στη συνέχεια, γίνεται ιδιαίτερη
αναφορά στην Ελλάδα, με την επισήμανση ότι εάν η υποτίμηση του ελληνικού
χρέους είχε γίνει σε δραχμές, θα είχαν βοηθηθεί κυρίως ορισμένοι
Έλληνες εξαγωγείς και θα είχε σημειώσει αξιοσημείωτη άνοδο ο ελληνικός
τουρισμός. Αυτό δεν θα είχε επιλύσει τα βασικά προβλήματα της Ελλάδας,
που περιλαμβάνουν ένα υπέρογκο κρατικό μισθολόγιο και μια τεράστια
φοροδιαφυγή, όπως υποστηρίζεται, αλλά τουλάχιστον θα είχε αποτραπεί η
ύφεση στην οποία βρίσκεται ακόμη και σήμερα.
Παράλληλα, τονίζεται
ότι από πλευράς νομοθεσίας, η πλειοψηφία των ελληνικών ομολόγων είχε
εκδοθεί υπό ελληνική νομοθεσία, με αποτέλεσμα η ελληνική κυβέρνηση να
παρέμβει και να υποχρεώσει τους κατόχους ομολόγων να ανταλλάξουν τα
ομόλογά τους για νέα, μικρότερης αξίας. Ωστόσο, για τα ομόλογα που
εκδόθηκαν υπό ξένη νομοθεσία, οι κάτοχοί τους δεν ενέδωσαν και σήμερα
και ένα τέτοιο ομόλογο εκτιμάται στα 90 λεπτά του ευρώ, ενώ το καλοκαίρι
του 2012, ανάλογο ομόλογο πωλείτο στα 14 λεπτά.
Στο μεταξύ, σε
δημοσίευμα του ειδησεογραφικού πρακτορείου Bloomberg γίνεται αναφορά
στην έκθεση του ΔΝΤ και, όπως υπογραμμίζεται η Ελλάδα εθεωρείτο μέχρι
πρόσφατα ότι θα επιτύγχανε τους στόχους, αλλά οι προβλέψεις αποδείχθηκαν
υπεραισιόδοξες. Σύμφωνα με το δημοσίευμα, η περισυλλογή φόρων
παρουσιάζει προβλήματα, η χώρα συνεχίζει να βρίσκεται σε ύφεση, ενώ η
πορεία ιδιωτικοποιήσεων εξελίσσεται βραδύτερα από ό,τι είχε σχεδιασθεί.
Το ελληνικό Υπουργείο Οικονομικών αντέδρασε αμέσως στις νέες προβλέψεις
του ΔΝΤ, υποστηρίζοντας ότι η ελληνική κυβέρνηση θα πράξει ό,τι είναι
δυνατό για να επιτύχει τον στόχο του 1,5%, είτε με την περικοπή δαπανών,
είτε με την αύξηση των φορολογικών εσόδων, είτε και με τα δύο.
Όπως αναφέρεται, οι περαίτερω περικοπές ωστόσο φαντάζουν πολιτικά
ανέφικτες, λόγω της δυσφορίας κατά των μέτρων λιτότητας. Η αδυναμία
επίτευξης των δημοσιονομικών στόχων θα μπορούσε επίσης να οδηγήσει στην
καθυστέρηση εκταμίευσης της δόσης από το ΔΝΤ και την Ευρωζώνη.
Τέλος, διατυπώνεται η άποψη ότι μια νέα ελληνική κρίση είναι εξαιρετικά πιθανή το επόμενο έτος.
ΠΗΓΗ:
http://www.imerisia.gr/article.asp?catid=26516&subid=2&pubid=113128314
-----------------------
At Risk: Currency Privilege of the Dollar
By FLOYD NORRIS
Not all government debt is created equal. Some governments get a much
better deal than others, and no one gets a better deal than the United
States.
The United States borrows in its own currency, and it borrows at
extremely low interest rates. It also borrows under its own laws, an
often overlooked advantage. Such a situation makes default — or at least
involuntary default — impossible because the government can print
dollars if need be. The value of the dollars it repays may be less than
the value of the dollars it borrows, but that is a risk the lenders
accept. The United States could change its laws, but it is trusted not
to abuse that right.
The perils of not having that flexibility became clear 80 years ago.
In 1933, when Franklin D. Roosevelt became president, the world was in the Great Depression
and many countries were devaluing their currencies in a desperate
attempt to stimulate exports and growth. That left the United States at a
disadvantage, and one of the first things the president did was to
persuade Congress to devalue the dollar.
The United States, like other countries, was on the gold standard. A
dollar was worth 25.8 grains of gold, and anyone with a dollar bill
could turn it in for that much gold. President Roosevelt and Congress
redefined the dollar as being worth 15.238 grains and made it illegal
for Americans to own gold coins. They were required to turn in their old
gold coins for dollars at the new rate.
United States government bonds of that era specified that the payment of
interest and principal was to be made in gold dollars, at the old rate.
Many private bonds had similar provisions. Congress overruled all those
provisions.
Was that legal?
In 1935, the Supreme Court answered. Chief Justice Charles Evans Hughes, with the support of four of his colleagues, concluded that the government could change the private contracts,
just as it could pass a bankruptcy law that enabled some debtors to
escape their obligations. But, he said, the government had no legal
right to amend its own bonds.
Then, in a pirouette that left legal scholars gaping, he ruled that
because it was no longer legal to own gold coins, a bondholder suffered
no actual losses. Had the government paid gold coins, the bondholder
would have been required to exchange them for dollars at the new rate.
It was not one of the great court decisions, at least in terms of legal
logic. But it was necessary for the health of the American economy.
Consider what would have happened if the gold clause had been upheld,
for both government and private debts. Suddenly any debtor who owed
$1,000 in gold dollars would owe $1,690 in new dollars. But incomes
would not have risen. Companies that were barely hanging on would have
gone broke. The Depression would have become much worse.
Robert H. Jackson, who would later become a Supreme Court justice, wrote
in 1941, “Any decision that upset the law as Congress had enacted it,
however sound in lawyer logic, could only breed widespread trade
mischief, commercial confusion and debtor disaster.” President Roosevelt
deemed the issue so important that he planned to defy the court if the government lost the suit.
I bring this up because most sovereign nations now do not have the
luxury the United States has. When they borrow internationally, they
borrow in a foreign currency. And the bonds often specify that any
disputes will be settled under foreign law — usually United States or
British law.
Many recent national defaults stemmed in part from those problems. The
1990s Asian financial crisis began in Thailand, which had tied its
currency to the United States dollar — and had borrowed a lot of
dollars. When it was forced to devalue its currency, the baht, it
suddenly owed far more baht than it had borrowed, not to mention far
more than it could hope to repay.
Greece provides an even better example. Had its debt been denominated in
Greek drachmas, its currency would have plunged in value when the Greek
crisis unfolded. A lower currency would have helped some Greek
exporters and brought in bargain-seeking foreign tourists. That would
not have solved Greece’s fundamental problems, which include a bloated
government payroll and immense tax evasion, but it would not have caused
the depression that the country is still in.
Instead, the debt was in euros. Unable to print them, or to borrow more
from suddenly fearful credit markets, Greece turned to the rest of
Europe for a bailout that came with harsh terms.
The issue of which nation’s law prevailed was also important. Most Greek
bonds had been issued under Greek law. Greece could, and did, change
that law and force bondholders to exchange their bonds for new ones
worth far less. But some of the bonds were issued under foreign law, and
those bondholders could not be forced to give in. There were not that
many such bonds outstanding, and in the end Greece continued to meet
those obligations. In the summer of 2012, one such bond traded for 14
cents on the euro. Today it trades for 90 cents.
Obviously any country would prefer to borrow from foreign investors in a
currency it can print, under laws it can change. But few countries have
enough credibility with investors to do that. Right now, there are
three: the United States, Japan and Britain.
Mario Draghi, the president of the European Central Bank, said on
Thursday that a deal was needed to protect world financial stability,
adding that “a short-term agreement produces less stability.” But, he
told the Economics Club of New York, “The world still does not believe
that the United States will not find a way out of this.”
That is why those who are warning of a disaster if there is a default on
American debt might turn out to be wrong, or at least premature. If it
is widely assumed that any default will be temporary, certain to be
fixed in the immediate future, the reaction could be muted.
But there is no guarantee of that. Why risk destroying the United
States’ world standing over a dispute about health insurance?
One part of the answer is that some Tea Party legislators ran for office
on a platform of hating the government, with language about how evil it
is.
That is extraordinary. There are people in the United States who view
oil companies, or investment banks, as evil and say they would like to
destroy them. None of them have managed to gain senior positions at
Exxon Mobil or Goldman Sachs. But right now people who feel that way
about the government seem to be able to prevent it from functioning if
they do not get their way.
Fortunately, as the economist Henry Kaufman noted this week, “The U.S.
dollar is the key reserve currency, and there is no immediate
alternative to it. Not the yen, not the euro, not the Chinese currency.”
That means it might take a lot of craziness to destroy the privileged
American position. It does not mean such destruction is impossible. The
members of Congress who support the government — presumably a large
majority — need to find a way to override those who oppose it.
In 1935, Justice James Clark McReynolds wrote for three of his
colleagues in denouncing the decision to allow the United States to
renege on its promises. His opinion concluded, “Loss of reputation for
honorable dealing will bring us unending humiliation; the impending
legal and moral chaos is appalling.”
He was wrong. By the time the decision came down, it was clear that the
repudiation of the gold clause had not destroyed the government’s
credit. Decades later, the economists Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S.
Rogoff would classify the repudiation as a default, but in 1935, most
Americans — and most foreign lenders — did not see it that way.
But the McReynolds forecast could come true if defaults become
acceptable in pursuit of partisan political advantage. Then the unique
position of the United States could erode or even vanish.
“To throw that away,” said Robert J. Barbera, the co-director of the
Center for Financial Economics at Johns Hopkins University, “would be
the single greatest mistake in American economic history.”
Floyd Norris comments on finance and the economy at nytimes.com/economix.
Source: NEW YORK TIMES, 11.10.2013,
http://www.nytimes.com/2013/10/11/business/at-risk-the-dollars-privilege-as-a-reserve-currency.html?pagewanted=2&_r=0
Σχετικά με τον συντάκτη της ανάρτησης:
Η ιστοσελίδα μας δημιουργήθηκε το 2008.Δείτε τους συντελεστές και την ταυτότητα της προσπάθειας. Επικοινωνήστε μαζί μας εδώ .
κανένα σχόλιο